Rural Credit in India; Issues and concerns
Describing India, the AIRCS had said, “India is essentially
Rural India and Rural India is virtually the cultivator, the
village handicraftsman and the agricultural labourer.” Rural
India, where 70% of all Indians live, still depends heavily on
agriculture. However, it is increasingly becoming diversified
market with a strong demand for credit for agriculture and
non-agricultural purposes, savings, insurance and money
transfers. In the next half hour or so, I will endeavour to trace
the sequence of events – both policy and institutional – during
*Managing Director, National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development (NABARD)
2
pre and post reform periods; dwell on the concerns relating to
financial exclusion and touch upon the SHG-Bank Linkage
model, which is a meaningful “inclusive response” to this
concern.
In the development strategy adopted by independent India, the
primary focus was growth with equity. Given an
understanding of the seasonal credit requirements of farm
operations, institutional credit was perceived fairly early in the
development process as a powerful tool for enhancing
production and productivity and for poverty alleviation. The
debates surrounding these issues, as also the suggested policy
directions were clearly spelt out in the report of the All India
Credit Survey Committee 1952.
To achieve the objectives of production and productivity, the
stance of policy towards rural credit was to ensure provision of
sufficient and timely credit at reasonable rates of interest to as
large a segment of the rural population as possible. The
strategy devised for the purpose rested on three pillars:
expansion of the institutional structure, directed lending to
disadvantaged borrowers and sectors and lower interest rates.
The chosen institutional vehicles for the task were
cooperatives, commercial banks and Regional Rural Banks
[RRBs]. Between 1950-69, the emphasis was on the promotion
of cooperatives, followed by a concerted push by commercial
3
banks during the post nationalisation period to establish
branches in the rural areas and the creation of new
institutional structures - RRBs in 1970s, NABARD in the
1980s and Local Area Banks in the late 1990s.
During this period, policy intervention at the macro level was
considered necessary to overcome factors which were
perceived as discouraging the flow of rural credit namely, high
cost of servicing, geographically dispersed customers, lack of
trained and motivated rural bankers etc. The Central Bank’s
policy response consisted of social control and nationalisation,
expansion of branch network into unbanked and underbanked
areas, evolution of Lead Bank Scheme and area
approach, enunciation of concept of targets for priority sector
and weaker section lending and special credit cum subsidy
programmes for the poorer sections of rural and urban areas.
Reaching credit at concessional rates was one of the important
elements of the strategy for deployment of rural credit. The
justification for offering credit at concessional rates to certain
categories of borrowers was based on the argument that farm
based investment activity in the short run does not always
yield a return which enables regular servicing of loans and at
the same time meet the minimum consumption requirements.
Since concessional lending impacted the profitability of rural
financial institutions [RFIs], a policy of cross subsidisation and
refinance from the RBI and later NABARD was put in place
4
simultaneously. This was broadly the policy framework, which
prevailed for over two decades.
There is a general consensus that the strategies followed
within this framework helped to build a broad based
institutional infrastructure for the delivery and deployment of
credit and also ensured a wider access of financial services to
the poor. To take a few indicators, the growth of credit during
1970-95 in real terms at 7 per cent was greater than
The annual growth in GDP
Real public agricultural capital formation at 3 per cent
Real private agricultural capital formation at 4 per cent
Real agricultural input spending at 6 per cent.
Resultantly, a much greater proportion of rural households
now have access to credit from these multiple formal
institutions compared to less than 10 per cent in the early
1950s.
The significant increase in the credit flow from institutional
sources brought forth a strong sense of expectation from the
public sector banks. However, this expectation could not be
sustained as the emphasis throughout was on achieving
certain quantitative targets. As a consequence, inadequate
attention was paid to the qualitative aspects of lending
resulting in loan defaults and erosion of repayment ethics, to a
5
greater or lesser extent, by all categories of borrowers. The
end result was a disturbing growth in overdues, which not
only hampered the recycling of scarce resources of banks, but
also affected profitability and viability of financial institutions.
Ultimately, financial deepening occurred but the development
impact of rural finance was blunted. In 1991, that is on the
eve of reforms, the rural credit delivery system was in poor
shape.
The basic aim of the financial sector reforms was to improve
the soundness, efficiency and productivity of all credit
institutions, including rural credit institutions whose financial
health was far from satisfactory. The reforms sought to
enhance the areas of commercial freedom, increase their
outreach to the poor and stimulate additional flows to the
sector. The reform programme also included far reaching
changes in the incentive regime through liberalising interest
rates for cooperatives and RRBs, relaxing controls on where,
for what purpose and whom rural financial institutions [RFIs]
could lend, introducing prudential norms and restructuring
and recapitalising of RRBs.
As a result of the reform process, the financial health of
commercial banks has improved in terms of parameters such
as capital adequacy, Non Performing Loans and return on
assets consistent with international standards for
classification of advances and prudential norms being applied
6
in almost all areas. However, commercial banks being more
focused on profitability, tend to cherry pick and give
comparatively less priority to marginal and sub-marginal
farmers.
The verdict on the 100 years old cooperatives is equally clear.
Despite being the dominant purveyors of production and
investment credit, their share has steadily declined over time.
As on date, they face serious problems of governance, solvency
and operational efficiency. A large segment of the Co-operative
Credit structure is multi-layered, under capitalised, overstaffed
and under-skilled, often with mounting non-performing
assets coupled with erosion of public deposits in certain cases.
As regards RRBs, barring a few, most have “turned around”
but are often characterised as ‘investment’ rather than credit
institutions and are perceived to have deviated from the
mandate of serving the poor and disadvantaged.
Overall, the concerns in relation to rural credit – other than
those relating to structural issues - are generally expressed in
terms of –
Inadequacy of credit
Constraints on timely availability of credit
High interest rates
Neglect of small and marginal farmers,
7
Low credit-deposit ratios in several states and
Continued presence of informal markets.
Speaking in this regard the RBI Governor has recently
remarked that these problems in regard to rural credit have
been well documented and several policy-approaches made to
remedy the situation. However, there is some element of
dissatisfaction that overall situation in regard to rural credit is
not improving to the desired level inspite of a series of actions.
He has added, and I quote, “It is a matter of concern that
cognizable success is eluding the policy-makers, at a time
when increasing commercialisation warrants a big thrust in
institutional credit to agriculture. There is thus a discernible
widespread intellectual recognition that while immediate
measures are undertaken to increase the flow of credit to
agriculture, there is a need to review the policy of rural credit
in a comprehensive and thorough manner.”
Issues and Concerns
There is no gainsaying the fact that the formal institutional
structure needs revamping to improve the efficiency of the
credit delivery system in rural areas.
In case of cooperatives, the Vaidyanathan Committee has
concluded that having regard to its outreach and potential,
recapitalisation could be undertaken so that the credit
8
channels for agricultural credit which are presently choked
could be declogged. The Vaidyanathan Committee has,
however, made it clear that recapitalisation should only be
considered if it is preceded by legal and institutional reforms
by State Governments aimed at making cooperatives
democratic and vibrant institutions run according to sound
business practices, governance standards and regulated at the
upper tiers by the RBI. The recommendations of the
Vaidyanathan Committee have been accepted by the GoI and
are in the process of receiving the approval of states.
The Long Term Structure is under similar examination by
Vaidyanathan Committee II.
In so far as commercial banks are concerned, competition and
search for higher returns is driving these banks to look for
profitable avenues and activities for lending such as financing
of contract farming, extending credit to the value chain,
financing traders and other intermediaries etc.
Simultaneously, we are witnessing the emergence of
institutional systems and products such as futures markets,
weather and crop insurance designed to minimise the risk of
lending. The direction is clear that commercial bank lending
will be to clientele which can bear the load of commercial
considerations. The coverage of excluded sections of the
population by them is currently being supported under
government sponsored schemes and targets for weaker
9
sections targets within the Priority Sector. The efficacy of this,
if measured by the yardstick of “collections”, is poor.
Merging and revamping of RRBs that are predominantly
located in tribal/ backward regions is seen as a potentially
significant institutional arrangement for financing the
excluded. Such an exercise is currently on and the State
Government’s and Sponsor Banks have to come together and
cooperate in this area.
In today’s lecture, I am not going to go into these areas
further. I will instead focus on the whole issue those who are
“financially excluded” in the rural areas and the extant
institutional response to them.
In this context, the recently published NSSO Survey (2003) -
relating to rural households is relevant.
The survey data point out that of the 147.90 million rural
households in the country, around 89.35 million households
or roughly 60% are cultivator households. Of these cultivator
households, 48.6% translating into 43.40 million households
are indebted to either formal sources or non-formal sources or
to both.
By implication, nearly 51% of cultivator households
translating into 45.95 million households or over 200 million,
poor are not indebted at all. It is pertinent to note that in the
10
non-indebted category, 88% of the households are headed by
SF/MFs with farm holdings of less than 2 hectares.
These and related data lead to certain conclusions :
The first is that as a proportion of total cultivator households
at 89.35 million, the coverage by formal sources – Banks,
MFIs, SHGs – is 24.31 million households or only 27%.
The next point is that the extent of coverage, the outreach of
the banking system at 24.31 million cultivator households,
shows a distinct bias towards households with larger farm
holdings. The data show that in regard to very small land
holdings of say around 25 cents, the formal system’s outreach
is hardly 23%, while in regard to farm holdings between 5 and
10 acres it is around 65%.
The third observation is that of the indebted households, if the
five states of Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Punjab, Kerala and
Karnataka - which show high levels of indebtedness to the
formal and informal system - are netted out, the overall level of
indebtedness falls by nearly 6 percentage points from 48.6 to
42.7. What is more significant is that the level of indebtedness
to only formal sources by cultivator households in the
remaining states drops to barely 20%.
11
The fourth conclusion is that the coverage by informal sources
is around 19.09 million households. Informal sector coverage
appears stable in some states, increasing in others and only
declining in some states in a patchy sort of way. There is a
need to understand the informal markets, the network of
relationships that support them and the nature and extent of
informal linkages with the formal system.
The fifth point is that hitherto, formal concern has been
primarily focused on the indebted poor. The stance of policy
and effort has been to find ways and means to increase the
flow of institutional credit to the indebted poor, reduce the
procedural and documentation hassles which characterize
lending to such poor and ensure that affordable credit is
reached to them at the appropriate time in adequate measure.
The most recent stipulation requiring banks to finance 100
new borrowers per branch on a continuing basis under the
GoI’s scheme for doubling of credit launched in 2004 is a step
towards including the excluded. The report is that the effort
has been significant and that up to March 2005, 7.88 million
new farmers had been financed by commercial banks, RRBs
and cooperatives taken together. However, this needs to be
validated through field studies because ground level data
indicate that there is some fuzziness regarding the way new
borrowers may have been defined.
12
The short point is that merely requiring bank branches to
finance 100 new farmers per annum will not be enough. If the
45.95 million rural households who are reported as not being
indebted at all have to be brought within the indebted fold, a
specific strategy will have to be designed for the purpose.
In order to design such a strategy, it is important to bear in
mind that 88% of the 46 million households in the nonindebted
category are headed by SF/MFs with farm holdings of
less than 2 hectares. We need to ask whether such farmers do
not need credit or do not get credit? And if the answer is in the
negative, we need to further ask whether it will be sufficient to
give them credit without taking supportive measures to ensure
their economic viability? I tend to believe that if this category
of the poor have to be financed, then there is an obligation to
create opportunities in which they can use the credit in a
meaningful way. This can be best done by creation of
production and employment opportunities in the real sector
through public investment.
We also need to ask whether the financing of sub-marginal
farmers is a credit plus issue? If it is a credit “plus” issue,
what does the “plus” comprise of ? Is it merely a grant based
support such as under an employment guarantee scheme or
should grant cum credit support be combined with investment
in human capital through education and health. Then again,
13
we know sub-marginal farmers migrate. What is the extent of
their migration? How can they be returned to land based and
non-farm activities? What measures can we take to build the
capacity and capability of such farmers? And is the banking
system capable of meeting this challenge through its present
mode of distribution of credit through the branch-banking
model? All this will entail, among others, the “mapping” of the
excluded by region and vocation. We are considering
mounting a survey for the purpose and I would request the
academics assembled here to assist us and give us their
counsel.
SHG - Bank - Linkage
Having delineated the position in regard to the excluded, let
me state that reaching the excluded is within the realm of
possibility through a variety of interventions including
innovations in product design and methods of delivery,
through better use of technology and related processes and
through institutional innovations backed by political and
executive will. However, for want of time, I will deal with only
one said intervention namely, the SHG-Bank Linkage model of
NABARD, which is an outstanding example of an innovation
leveraging on community based structures and existing
banking institutions.
The SHG- Bank linkage was conceived at a time when the
financial sector reforms were motivating policy planners to
14
search for innovative products and strategies for delivering
financial services to the poor in a sustainable manner
consistent with high repayment rates. The search for these
alternatives started with internal introspection regarding the
innovations which the poor had been traditionally making, to
meet their financial services needs. It was found that the
poor tend to come together in a variety of informal ways for
pooling their savings and dispensing small and unsecured
loans at varying costs to group members on the basis of need.
The essential contribution of NABARD in the SHG-Bank
programme was to recognise this process, which had been
catalysed by NGOs, and to create an interface of these
informal arrangements of the poor with the banking system.
The SHG-Bank Linkage Programme started as an Action
Research Project in 1989. Positive field level findings led, in
1992, to the setting up of a Pilot Project. The project was
designed as a “Partnership Model” between three agencies,
viz., the SHGs, banks and Non Governmental Organisations
(NGOs).
SHGs were to facilitate collective decision-making by the
poor and provide 'doorstep banking';
Banks as wholesalers of credit, were to provide the
resources and
15
NGOs were to act as agencies to organise the poor, build
their capacities and facilitate the process of empowering
them.
Achievements
The programme has come a long way from the pilot stage of
financing 500 SHGs across the country. Of the total SHGs
formed, more than 1.6 million have been linked with 35,294
bank branches of 560 banks in 563 districts across 30 States
of the Indian Union. Cumulatively, they have so far accessed
credit of Rs.6.86 billion. About 24 million poor households,
translating into nearly 120 million poor, of which around a
third belong to the SC/ST category, have gained access to the
formal banking system through the programme.
Given these quantitative achievements, what has been the
impact of the programme. Cumulative experience and field
findings show that :
The programme has reduced the incidence of poverty
through increase in income, helped the poor to build assets
and thereby reduce their vulnerability.
It has enabled households that have access to it to spend
more on education than non-client households. Families
16
participating in the programme have reported better school
attendance and lower drop out rates.
It has empowered women by enhancing their contribution
to household income, increasing the value of their assets
and generally by giving them better control over decisions
that affect their lives.
In certain areas, it has reduced child mortality, improved
maternal health and the ability of the poor to combat
disease through better nutrition, housing and health -
especially among women and children.
Again, in certain areas, it has contributed to a reduced
dependency on informal money lenders and other noninstitutional
sources.
Finally, it has offered space for different stakeholders to
innovate, learn and replicate. As a result, some NGOs have
added micro-insurance products to their portfolios, a couple
of federations have experimented with undertaking
livelihood activities and grain banks have been successfully
built into the SHG model in the eastern region. SHGs in
some areas have employed local accountants for keeping
their books; and IT applications are now being explored by
almost all for better MIS, accounting and internal controls.
17
Given these findings, what have been the learnings?
The first learning is that the “poor are bankable”. When
this is viewed in context of the attitudinal constraints that
characterised bankers on the eve of the linkage programme,
one can appreciate what an immense learning point this
has been.
The second key learning is that the poor, organised into
SHGs, are ready and willing to partner mainstream
financial institutions and banks on their part find their
SHG portfolios “safe” and “performing”.
The third learning is that despite being contra intuitive, the
poor can and do save in a variety of ways and the creative
harnessing of such savings is a key success factor.
The fourth learning is that successful programmes are
those that afford opportunity to stakeholders to contribute
to it on their own terms. When this happens, the chances
of success multiply manifold.
The fifth learning is that when a programme is built on
existing structures, it leverages all strengths. Thus,
because the SHG-Bank programme is built upon the
existing banking infrastructure, it has obviated the need for
18
the creation of a new institutional set-up or introduction of
a separate legal and regulatory framework. Since financial
resources are sourced from regular banking channels and
members’ savings, the programme bypasses issues relating
to regulation and supervision. Lastly, since the Group acts
as a collateral substitute, the model neatly addresses the
irksome problem of provision of collateral by the poor.
The last learning is that central banks, apex development
banks and governments have an important role in creating
the enabling environment and putting appropriate policies
and interventions in position which enable rapid upscaling
of efforts consistent with prudential practices. But for this
opportunity, no innovation can take place.
Challenges:
Notwithstanding these valuable learning points it is clear that
if the programme is to measure up to the task of reaching the
excluded 46 million non-indebted cultivator households, it will
have to meet the challenges confronting it. For this it must
introspect and develop within itself flexibility which will
permit, indeed encourage, innovation in design and practice.
What are the challenges which the movement faces today?
19
The first challenge is the skewed distribution of SHGs across
States. About 60% of the total SHG credit linkages in the
country are concentrated in the Southern States. However, in
States which have a larger share of the poor, the coverage is
comparatively low.
The second challenge is that having formed SHGs and having
linked them to banks, how can they be induced to graduate
into matured levels of enterprise, how can they be induced to
factor in livelihood diversification, how can they increase their
access to the supply chain, linkages to the capital market and
to appropriate/ production and processing technologies.
The SHG Bank-Linkage programme also needs to introspect
whether it is sufficient for SHGs to only meet the financial
needs of their members, or whether there is a further
obligation on their part to meet the non-financial requirements
necessary for setting up businesses and enterprises. In my
view, we must meet both.
The third challenge is how to ensure the quality of SHGs in an
environment of exponential growth. Due to the rapid growth
of the SHG Bank Linkage Program, the quality of SHGs has
come under stress. This is reflected particularly in indicators
such as the poor maintenance of books and accounts etc. In
20
my assessment, significant financial investment and technical
support is required for meeting this challenge.
The fourth challenge is that the programme success has
motivated the Government to borrow its design features and
incorporate them in their poverty alleviation programme. This
is welcome but the fact is that the Government’s Programme
(SGSY) has an inbuilt subsidy element which tends to attract
members and cause them to leave their original SHG-Bank
linked groups and migrate to the SGSY groups generally for
the wrong reasons.
Micro level studies have also raised concerns regarding the
process through which groups are formed under the SGSY.
The finding is that in many cases members are induced to
come together not for self help, but for subsidy. I would urge
a debate on this as there is a need to resolve the tension
between SGSY and linkage programme groups. One answer
could be to place the subsidy element in the SGSY programme
with NABARD. The subsidy could then be utilised for
providing indirect support for purposes such as sensitisation,
capacity building, exposure visits to successful models, etc.
A derivative of the above is perhaps the need to extend the
above debate to understanding and defining the role of the
State Governments vis-à-vis the linkage programme. It is
21
clear that on the one hand, the programme would not have
achieved its outreach and scale, but for the proactive
involvement of the State Governments. On the other hand,
many State Governments have been overzealous to achieve
scale and access without a critical assessment of the
manpower and skill sets available with them for forming, and
nurturing groups and handholding and maintaining them over
time. This needs to be studied and addressed.
The emergence of SHG Federations has thrown up another
challenge. On the one hand, such federations represent the
aggregation of collective bargaining power, economies of scale,
and are a fora for addressing social & economic issues; on the
other hand there is evidence to show that every additional tier,
in addition to increasing costs, tends to weaken the primaries.
There is a need to study the best practices in the area and
evolve a policy by learning from them.
Before closing, let me use this opportunity to sound two notes
of caution. One, that while we are upbeat about the success
achieved and the potential that the SHG – Linkage programme
offers to reach the poor, we need to be realistic not to view this
instrument as a one-stop solution either for rural credit or for
all developmental problems. The programme has certain
inherent limitations and these should be addressed. The
second is that the issues of rural credit cannot be addressed
22
without strengthening the credit delivery system. It is for this
reason that the efforts under way to strengthen the
institutional mechanisms to facilitate lending to this sector will
have to be continued with vigour and supported with great
sincerity by State Governments. I have no doubt that if State
Governments lend their executive and political support,
cooperatives and RRBs can be revitalized and converted into
effective instruments for serving the public good. That this
can be done was articulated by the Hon’ble Prime Minister at
the last meeting of the National Development Council.
Speaking to us, he said, “Today, India is at a historic point in
its development trajectory. As I said in my opening remarks
yesterday, we are now at a point in time where we can deliver
growth at a rate of 7% - 8%. At this point in time, owing to the
developments over the last two decades, there are no external
constraints to the growth of our country. It is very much in
the realm of possibility for this country to become a
prosperous nation, rid of the perennial scourges of poverty,
ignorance and disease. The world is today looking at India
with great interest as the saga of our development and rise to
prominence on the international stage unfolds. Rare are such
moments in history when a nation suddenly captures the
imagination of the world.
23
In such circumstances, if there are any constraints, these are
purely internal. Our success in living up to our potential
depends solely only on us. No external force can be blamed if
we do not rise up to everyone’s expectations. Therefore, it is
incumbent on all of us to ensure that we realize this potential.
It is this vision of a resurgent India that must guide our
actions while discharging our duties.”
On this note of hope for a better tomorrow, I take leave of you.
Thanking you once again for having given me this honour and
opportunity today.
-------------------------
No comments:
Post a Comment